The Demic Atlas Project:
Toward a Non-State-Based Approach to Mapping Global Economic and Social Development
by Martin W. Lewis, Jake Coolidge, and Anne Fredell
by Martin W. Lewis
From: GeoCurrents
9 August 2011
GeoCurrents has taken a summer hiatus to
create a new cartographic framework for analyzing socio-economic development.
This project is a collaborative effort involving three team-members: Jake
Coolidge, a geospatial historian at Stanford
University’s Spatial History Lab;
Anne Fredell, a Stanford
University undergraduate;
and myself.
The Spatial History Lab at Stanford, which has provided extensive technical assistance, will eventually publish the maps as an on-line document. GeoCurrents will also post maps from the project, as well as commentary on the process. Beginning today, I will discuss both the intellectual rationale for such an atlas and the problems that we have encountered in creating it.
The Spatial History Lab at Stanford, which has provided extensive technical assistance, will eventually publish the maps as an on-line document. GeoCurrents will also post maps from the project, as well as commentary on the process. Beginning today, I will discuss both the intellectual rationale for such an atlas and the problems that we have encountered in creating it.
The Non-Comparability of Sovereign
States
Global economic and social comparisons are
almost always made within the framework of sovereign states. Countries are
numerically ranked against each other on such measurements as per capita GDP,
literacy, and longevity, much as students are tallied together on a class grade
sheet. If one wants to know what part of the world is the richest, healthiest,
or best educated—or the opposite—the answer will generally come in
the form of a national name. Whether on maps, tables, or charts, the country is
the category that counts.
Our atlas starts from the premise that,
while sovereign states are certainly the essential units of the geopolitical
order, they are not necessarily appropriate units of socio-economic comparison.
In actuality, countries are ill suited for such purposes.
For starters, they are simply not comparable entities, varying enormously in both area and population. We know this, but we rarely let it truly sink in. Consider the discrepancy between China, with 1.3 billion inhabitants, and Tuvalu, with ten thousand. Comparing these two independent states is like weighing a single person against a city of 130,000.
For starters, they are simply not comparable entities, varying enormously in both area and population. We know this, but we rarely let it truly sink in. Consider the discrepancy between China, with 1.3 billion inhabitants, and Tuvalu, with ten thousand. Comparing these two independent states is like weighing a single person against a city of 130,000.
To appreciate the absurdity of such an exercise, consider
what it would mean to compare either with a hypothetical entity equally far
removed in the opposite direction. A country as small relative to Tuvalu as Tuvalu
is to China would be
inhabited by one twelfth of a person, while a country as large relative to China as China
is to Tuvalu
would be a galactic polity of 160 trillion inhabitants.
No serious study would ever make such a comparison, spanning more than five orders of magnitude. Yet when it comes to assessing the economic and social conditions of the world, making such gargantuan leaps in scale is the price we pay for using country-based data.
No serious study would ever make such a comparison, spanning more than five orders of magnitude. Yet when it comes to assessing the economic and social conditions of the world, making such gargantuan leaps in scale is the price we pay for using country-based data.
Relying on an inappropriate geopolitical
framework for social and economic analysis can quickly leads one astray.
Consider the CIA World Factbook’s
list of countries by average longevity (a list that is replicated in Wikipedia).
Surprisingly, one country stands well above all others: Monaco.
Whereas twenty-four entries
are crowded in the eighty- to eighty-four year life-expectancy range, miniscule
Monaco reaches almost ninety (89.7). Intriguingly, the third and fourth places
are also occupied by European microstates: San
Marino and Andorra. As it turns out, most of
the top positions on the CIA list are taken by small, tiny, and
smaller-than-tiny polities located in Europe, eastern Asia, and the Caribbean.
As a result, some of the seemingly
healthiest and wealthiest major countries do not rank particularly high on the
longevity index. Germany
comes in 32nd out of 223, the United Kingdom
is 36th, and the United
States trails well back at 50th. A quick
glance at the table might make it seem as if the U.S. were bested in life expectancy
by almost a quarter of the world.
In actuality, the total population of the forty-nine top entries is less than ten per cent of the global sum. That is not exactly a stellar showing for the U.S., especially considering the fact that it is bested by several much poorer countries, including Jordan and Bosnia. Still, the fiftieth-place position indicated by the Factbook is misleadingly low.
In actuality, the total population of the forty-nine top entries is less than ten per cent of the global sum. That is not exactly a stellar showing for the U.S., especially considering the fact that it is bested by several much poorer countries, including Jordan and Bosnia. Still, the fiftieth-place position indicated by the Factbook is misleadingly low.
The preponderance of microstates in the
upper reaches of the longevity list could easily lead to erroneous deductions
about country size and public health. The correlation, after all, is striking:
sixteen of the top fifty entries on the list have fewer than 100,000 people,
while none of the bottom fifty do. One might reasonably conclude that small
polities are somehow better able to meet the health needs of their citizens
than their more populous neighbors.
Could political devolution enhance
longevity?
Any such conclusion would be nonsensical.
The people of Andorra, a
feudal remnant in the Pyrenees sandwiched between France
and Spain,
may live longer than the average residents of neighboring countries, but they
do not out-live the inhabitants of adjacent French and Spanish districts. Put
differently, if all Europe were divided into states the size of Monaco (population 36,000), Monaco’s sizable advantage
would instantly vanish, as other tiny, wealthy enclaves located in salubrious
environments would boast similar longevity figures.
In the end, the CIA rankings are compromised
by comparing incommensurable entities. But it is not just the World Factbook that is at fault here.
Virtually all numerical assessments of global development shoehorn
socio-economic data into the same geopolitical categories, where size means
nothing. In the world of international statecraft, to be sure, all sovereign
countries are treated as theoretically equivalent individuals, regardless of
their population or power. Such pretense may be necessary in the halls of
diplomacy, but it does not help anyone grasp the complex patterns of social and
economic disparity found across the surface of the earth.
While most global comparisons are made
strictly within the framework of sovereign states, which number slightly fewer
than 200, the CIA World Factbook
employs an expanded list, noting 223 “countries” in its longevity
chart. The additional entries are actually dependent territories, most
of which
boast impressive life-expectancy figures (Cayman Islands, Bermuda,
Gibraltar,
the Isle of Man, etc.).
Such an inclusive approach is beginning to be followed by other major data sources as well, no doubt from a desire to be fair and comprehensive. Just because Greenland and Guernsey lack full independence is no reason to consign them to statistical oblivion. In the process, however, the problem of incomparability is compounded.
Such an inclusive approach is beginning to be followed by other major data sources as well, no doubt from a desire to be fair and comprehensive. Just because Greenland and Guernsey lack full independence is no reason to consign them to statistical oblivion. In the process, however, the problem of incomparability is compounded.
While all of the world’s independent
countries (barring the anomalous Vatican
City) have at least 10,000 inhabitants, many
dependencies are much smaller. Wikipedia’s inclusive “list of countries
by population” bottoms out with 224th-place Pitcairn, which boasts all
of
fifty residents at last count. Although Pitcairn does not make the CIA’s
longevity table, a number of other miniscule dependencies do. Adding
these
micro-units clutters the list while providing little information of
value.
The biggest distortion that results from
using states or quasi-states as all-encompassing spatial containers for
socio-economic comparison is that lightly populated areas might receive precise
scrutiny, while some of the world’s most populous places are subjected to
extraordinarily crude aggregation. As a consequence, the residents of small
countries literally count for more than do the residents of large ones.
An
equal appraisal of individual polities, in other words, results in an
intrinsically unfair weighting of the individual persons within those polities.
In the World Factbook’s tabulation, the average inhabitant of the British
dependency of Saint Helena, Ascension and Tristan da Cunha (population 5,660)
is inadvertently deemed twenty-six million times more attention-worthy than the
average resident of China.
China and India,
the world’s demographic giants, are particularly ill-served by being
treated as singularities. Not only do these two countries have huge
populations—more than a third of the global total between them—but
both are characterized by vast regional disparities. As a result, numbers given
for China and India
as a whole are almost worthless.
When overall per capita GDP is calculated in terms of purchasing power parity, China’s $7,500 figure ranks well below the global average of $11,100. But the commercial core areas of eastern China, increasingly vital drivers of the world economy, evince per capita GDP figures well above the world average, reaching $13,000 in Jiangsu, $18,500 in Shanghai, and $46,000 in Hong Kong.
When overall per capita GDP is calculated in terms of purchasing power parity, China’s $7,500 figure ranks well below the global average of $11,100. But the commercial core areas of eastern China, increasingly vital drivers of the world economy, evince per capita GDP figures well above the world average, reaching $13,000 in Jiangsu, $18,500 in Shanghai, and $46,000 in Hong Kong.
In contrast, Guizhou
in China’s
south-central interior produced only $3,400 worth of goods and services per
person in 2010, a
figure comparable to that of war-ravaged Iraq. In global comparative terms, China
spans the gap between the rich and poor worlds. Grasping such regional
differences is essential for understanding the economy of China, and hence that of the world.
Yet in the standard method of tabulating and portraying global economic data,
such disparities remain invisible.*
The depiction of the world as divided into
supposedly comparable individual geopolitical entities reaches its extreme form
in a number of almanacs and children’s atlases in which each country is
accorded its own map and page or two of text. In such cases, China typically receives a bit more attention
than Tuvalu—but
not much.
The genre is nicely parodied in Our
Dumb World: The Onion’s Atlas of the Planet Earth. Its
mocking caption for San Marino, whose 32,000 people inhabit twenty-four square
miles, reads, “These A**holes Don’t Belong In An Atlas,”
while the text focuses on the absurdity of elevating such an insignificant
piece of territory to the same level as that of major countries. A sidebar,
entitled “A Marino You Should Care About,” claims that “Miami
Dolphins quarterback Dan Marino achieved more during his 17-year Hall of Fame
career than the ‘nation’ of San Marino has managed to
accomplish since A.D. 301.”
In actuality, the history of the little state is rather more illustrious than
that; in early modern Europe, San Marino was often highlighted by geographers
because of the fact that it was a rare republic (officially, “the most
serene republic”) during a period of monarchical dominance. But the
humorists at The Onion have
a point; putting San Marino
at the same level as Italy,
let alone India,
is an exercise in absurdity.
How might such absurdity be avoided? This
is a complex issue that will occupy the pages of GeoCurrents over the next
several weeks.
* Hong Kong,
a Special Administrative Region of China, with its own laws and currency, is
usually tabulated separately from the rest of the country.
If you enjoyed this post, consider sharing
it with those whom you think would enjoy it as well, using
the social buttons above. If you're a fan of GeoCurrents and would like updates on our newest posts, you can
receive them easily by subscribing to the GeoCurrents
RSS feed, Twitter feed, or Facebook Page.
No hay comentarios:
Publicar un comentario